Ned Rossiter: Whose Democracy?
Information Flows, NGOs and the Predicament of Developing States. |
Everyone likes to claim their organisations operate
in ways that adhere to basic democratic principles. The complex of informational
relations between African states, supranational entities, corporations,
civilian populations and NGOs is defined by various scalar tensions that
seriously undermine the constitutive dimensions of a democratic polity.
Herein lies the logic of uneven modernities. This talk considers the paradoxical
role played by NGOs in developing civic infrastructures, and suggests that
greater focus needs to be placed by NGOs on securing intellectual property
rights for developing states as the condition of political and economic
sovereignty within informational and biotech economies.
Introduction There's no question that non-governmental organisations (NGOs)
have more often than not played vital roles in fulfilling a range of humanitarian
related tasks in numerous states that have been subject to the ravages of
colonialism, environmental disasters, agricultural failure, civil wars and
genocide, internal political and social instability, currency crises, or
a combination of all of these. In many instances, NGOs have filled a gap
in the vacuum within developing, transitionary or "quasi-states" who, for
various reasons, do not have the capacity to provide social services for
their populations. As a result of this, NGOs entrench an extant condition
whereby developing states may often not be equipped with the sort of institutional
infrastructures and sociopolitical formations - namely, a domestic capitalist
bourgeoisie and civil society traditions - that have enabled the formation
of democracy within the project of nation building, as witnessed in the
West. As such, many developing states do not have the sort of structural
conditions in place to experience the unfolding of modernity. Or rather,
in a dialectical sense, these states have indeed experienced forms of modernity
that are radically dissimilar in spatio-temporal and ontological ways from
that experienced by and within western liberal democracies.
In many respects, the material conditions of developing states have enabled
the possibility of a range of conditions and experiences in advanced economies
that could be considered as privileges constituted by legitimately enacted
violence. A large part of this experience can be accounted for by referring
to the histories of colonialism - a project whereby hegemonic states are
able to secure the material resources and imaginary dimensions necessary
for their own consolidation and prosperity. These histories have been well
documented, but it is worth keeping the spectre of colonialism in mind when
discussing the situation of developing states, NGOs and informational economies
- the subject of my paper today.
My argument in this paper is that in order for developing states to secure
political sovereignty, it is first necessary to obtain a degree of economic
power. (In this sense my thesis is fairly traditional or conservative, even
crude.) I suggest that a key way in which economic power can be obtained
for indigenous peoples and developing states is through intellectual property
rights as they pertain to cultural production and biological knowledge.
I maintain that the state form is an important one in the process of democracy
formation, and that it is a mistake to see the state as obsolete within
globalised informational economies. Furthermore, I do not see the state
as necessarily antagonistic to the functioning of informational economies.
Indeed, the discursive figure of the state is built in to member obligations
of the WTO's Agreement on Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property
Rights (TRIPS) in 1995 as a key administrative, legal and political actor.
The challenge is to reform IP laws in such a way that meets the needs and
interests of indigenous peoples and those in developing states.
To this end, my argument has attracted hostility from cyber-libertarians
and sectors in open source movements who persist with that rather ridiculous
mantra "information wants to be free", as though there is some ontology
to the technicity of the net independent of the social relations which make
the net intelligible. Cyber-libertarians and IT open source movements overlook
two key things when they advocate the free flow of information: 1) the world
is not a software program: i.e. other forms of knowledge also exist, and
the extent to which information is accessible so that it might then be transformed
into knowledge depends to a large extent on degrees of cultural capital,
not only IT access. 2) To promote and argue for IP rights for indigenous
peoples and developing states does not preclude the ongoing circulation
of information within those communities. Rather, it ensures that knowledge
specific to those communities is not exploited by transnational corporations
(TNCs), who 'own approximately 90% of technology and product patents in
the world, and up to 80% of technology and product patents in developing
countries'. Furthermore, such a pro-IP position recognises that indigenous
peoples and social formations within developing states are quite adept at
functioning both within customary law as well as international contract
law as it pertains to proprietary rights over cultural production and biological
knowledge. That is, we shouldn't overlook the way indigenous peoples engage
in bi-modal regimes of practice. To do so is to relegate indigenous peoples
and those in developing countries to nostalgic and violent discourses of
pre-modern timeless time.
To a large extent, the anti-IPR response by cyber-libertarians has been
shaped by a North American political tradition that is hostile to and suspicious
of government regulation and intervention. This, we are all familiar with.
And in many respects the cyber-libertarian position colludes with the ideology
of liberalism, as it figures in mainstream US political traditions that
place a primacy on the individual over and above the collective. And it
smacks of hypocrisy and righteousness to hear such objections from cyber-libertarians
when many occupy positions of privilege, frequently accompanied by salaried
day jobs associated with computer programming, data surveillance or software
development.
Finally, my argument with regard to NGOs is that while NGOs occupy a significant
structural relationship with supranational entities, state apparatuses and
local communities - thus constituting what Castells terms the new form of
a "network state" - they do not exploit their political leverage in any
extensive sense by pursuing IP policy reforms and negotiating with government
on behalf of securing intellectual property rights for local communities.
It strikes me, then, that this is a key direction for NGOs to pursue if
they are to maintain an advocacy role for civilian populations in developing
states.
Scalar tensions
In taking up roles traditionally the reserve of the state, NGOs condition
the possibility of three key features, all of which undermine the economic
and political sovereignty of emerging states.
Firstly, with the logic of flexible production, accumulation and consumption
that has corresponded with the emergence of new ICTs and the capacity to
organise social relations in the form of networks, we have seen an increasing
liberalisation of the state and the market. And with this process we have
seen liberalisation decoupled from democracy, where the latter ensured a
degree of transparency and accountability from the former: this well and
truly vanished with the onset of the "new economy", as we've seen in the
shonky accountancy methods of companies associated with the tech-wreck,
Enron being the most obvious example.
The kind of inflated economic returns in the form of debt management on
the balance sheet has been the basis for neoliberal states to feel secure
in their ongoing pursuit of deregulation and privatisation. Furthermore,
hegemonic states and the supranational organisations they are aligned with
have been unrelenting in imposing this structural logic of neoliberalism
upon developing states as a condition of receiving financial aid from the
IMF, World Bank and the like. In the case of developing states this has
led to a range of structural conditions that emulate some of the structural
arrangements peculiar to neoliberal modes of organising social relations,
state bureaucracies and corporate practices.
NGOs often find themselves involved in activities in the realm of education,
providing training and literacy skills to local communities. Such activities
may be secondary to the key mission of NGOs. As Rececca Knuth notes with
regard to information flows in complex emergencies, 'There is an acute awareness
among relief organizations that short-term intervention to save lives must
be supplemented by long-term reconstruction initiatives that reconstitute
local systems and prevent future crises'. However, there is a high risk
that such long-term initiatives become fragmented and reproduced, at best,
as a series of short-term interventions undertaken by an assortment of relief
agencies in as much as there is no guarantee that NGOs have either the financial
resources or enduring personnel to commit to long-term reconstruction projects.
Furthermore, the state no longer holds a structural relation to civilian
populations. This immediately begins to undermine the constitutive dimensions
of modern democracy. For example, the task of the modern university corresponded
with the project of nation building, of establishing what Benedict Anderson
called an 'imagined community'. In modern times, the university has been
a key actor in the process of democracy formation within the West. The university
cultivated an informed and knowledgeable bourgeoisie and citizenry, trained
with the capacity to deliberate over the political and social life of the
nation. The university also played a key role in the development of civil
society insofar as it occupied a critical space independent of the state.
Today, of course, we have seen this role seriously eroded as universities
and academics working within them are constituted within a neoliberal paradigm
as "pseudo-corporate" institutions and "post-intellectuals".
When NGOs become responsible for educating civilian populations, an almost
perverse correlation with the civilising mission of the coloniser kicks
in. In fact, I would go so far as to say that at a structural level NGOs
occupy a similar territory as TNCs, both of whom contribute to a process
of recolonisation of postcolonial states. This can result in tensions between
well-meaning NGOs and local populations over the kind of political, social
and cultural values attached to the techniques of education. Moreover, the
state foregoes the hegemonic process of negotiating sociopolitical values
with civilian populations as they are articulated through and within the
educational apparatuses. As such, a key dimension of democracy formation
is dispensed with.
Secondly, in adopting the task of educating civilian populations about procedures
for clearing landmines - as in the case of the German Initiative to Ban
Landmines, to take one example - we see a process at work that is similar
to the neoliberal technique of outsourcing. At a structural level, then,
the state "leapfrogs" straight into a neoliberal frame, bypassing the temporal
and spatial experiences of the modern welfare state. In other words, developing
states are structurally positioned whether they like it or not in flexible
modes of delivery, hence creating a dependency relation on external providers
as distinct from domestically developed systems of learning and the social
formations and cultural values that attend such a process.
In this sense, NGOs, when involved in auxiliary roles such as education,
undermine one of the traditional roles of the state. As such, NGOs are assisting
in the formation of conditions that also benefit the interests of TNCs,
which seek to obtain by any means possible conditions that enable unilinear
flows of capital, unrestricted by domestically determined regulatory interventions
by the state. Furthermore, the presence of NGOs, as external providers of
services traditionally the reserve of the state, reinforces the sort of
conditions associated with IMF and World Bank monetary loans and their structural
adjustment programs. This raises serious questions with regard to NGOs who
claim to occupy an advocacy position on behalf of civilian interests. Indeed,
I would suggest that the very notion of civil society as a sort of autonomous
space is brought into question as NGOs find themselves in a paradoxical
field of tensions in which they are at once bound to local communities whilst
assisting in direct and indirect ways the interests of TNCs and supranational
governance.
As many of you will recall, a lively debate tracked this issue on the nettime
mailing list February 1997 with a number of postings critiquing the Soros
network and the inter-relationships between NGOs, corporations and civil
society. Some of the issues and critiques from that time were synthesised
in an interview with Saskia Sassen by Geert Lovink in 1999. On the issue
of accountability, Lovink noted that 'One of the problems of NGOs - especially
if they are linked to large international organizations - is that for people
on the ground, and even for governments, they are no longer accountable
for what they do. They can move very quickly and in many ways can behave
like finance capital'. In this sense, NGOs again can be seen to model some
of the dynamics of TNCs and reproduce techniques of organisation peculiar
to neoliberalism. Deconstructing the question of accountability, Sassen
importantly notes:
… accountable to what and for what? In some cases, the fact that some of
these organizations are not accountable is actually better, because it means
that a different kind of political project can be enacted - whereas if an
organization is accountable, it often means being accountable to existing
value systems, which in some cases are the very ones best avoided. However,
many of the big NGOs are profoundly accountable - by which I mean they are
accountable in the kinds of ways and to the kinds of entities one might
not want to demand accountability for or to.
Then, relating the question back to her own research on the architecture
of global finance and the need to 'invent new systems for accountability
and accountability for different kinds of aims in some of these systems',
Sassen elaborates on the problematic of "transparency":
There is an architecture, there are certain standards the players adhere
to; and there is transparency, the famous term "transparency", which implies
something that's intrinsically good. But what is it? It is accountability
to shareholders and their short-term profit. But do we always want this
kind of accountability? No - including from global finance - so we're presented
with the challenge of discovering new types of accountability, new ways
of thinking the question of accountability - accountability to a larger
public good, and so on.
For the purposes of this paper, I want to highlight that while NGOs may
procure tactical benefits from an absence of accountability, this has to
be weighed against the correspondence such a system of organisation has
with informational secrecy by corporations. The consequence of this is fundamentally
antithetical to the "transparency" assumed of conventional notions of democracy.
Or perhaps what is needed now within theoretical reflections are new concepts
of democracy as it figures in post-governmental networks. That is, can democracy
be conceived in "post-political" times in which, according to Hardt, there
is a 'withering of civil society'?
Thirdly, the sidelining of the state is also significant at a political
level, since there is no institutional residue or collective memory of things
being otherwise. And at an imaginary level, the possibility of different
forms of political organisation that correspond with the space of the nation
is not there. While the neoliberal state has seen the erosion of traditional
differences between the left and the right and the emergence of "third way"
style politics, I think it is premature to overlook the political function
of pseudo-corporate institutions such as the university and the persistence
of trade unions: these are institutions that are part of what I'm calling
a collective residual memory that contribute to what Ghassan Hage has called
the possibility of spaces of hope. Having said this, I wouldn't want to
rule out the potential for alternative political models emerging from indigenous
modes of political organisation.
In short, I hope the above examples gesture towards, if not convincingly
demonstrate, the paradoxical role of NGOs within quasi-states: probably
against their best wishes, NGOs are situated in such a way that assists
in the imposition of neoliberal systems of organisation upon developing
states. As such, these states are occluded from the sort of modernising
experiences and processes - its times and its spaces - that have been fundamental
to the constitution of liberal democracy in the West. I'll return to the
question of democracy in the final section of this paper, once I establish
the political role of IP rights for developing states and their civilian
populations.
Informational flows, scale and borders
With the advent of new ICTs, particularly the internet, NGOs have been able
to consolidate and expand themselves, creating new alliances by networking
with each other through horizontally organised information flows. As I noted
earlier, the rise of NGOs has coincided with the emergence of globalised
economies. Similarly, the net has enabled NGOs to interface with local,
state, military and supranational entities. This might give the impression
that distinctions in scale disappear, and that tension between and within
these sectors no longer prevail. Certainly this is not the case, since NGOs
often enough contest the powers of the state in the interests of the "the
people" (a politically dubious figure at best). With their enhanced capacity
to gather and disseminate information, NGOs have obtained greater legitimacy
as political actors, often challenging the sovereignty of authoritarian
governments. The horizontal expansion of informational flows has led a number
of scholars to claim that a new state form has emerged - a form which Castells
has termed the "network state", one that international relations theorist
Martin Shaw calls the "global state", and a form that Hardt and Negri attribute
to the "post-political" manifestation of "Empire".
The extent to which such a new state form can be called democratic is highly
questionable, however. Moreover, such a form has not fared well for communicative
relations for those civilian populations deprived of adequate IT infrastructures;
nor should an intensification in informational flows be assumed to correspond
with open systems of communication. The commercialisation of the net and
its regulation via domain names and intellectual property regimes functions
to close information flows. But as I argue below, depending on the extent
of reform, IPRs can be used as a strategic political architecture that at
once maintains the flow of information within informal networks, while securing
a closure against external exploitation.
The lack of any extensive IT infrastructure militates against the possibility
of translocal networks within and across African states, though there are
indications that this is changing. For the time being, a reproduction of
dependency goes on in which the relatively few users connected to the few
metropolitan ISPs within African states are dependent on the expansive networks
in Europe and the US for their information flows. It's for this reason that
'133 developing countries have asked the United Nations to maintain radio
stations and other traditional media as a means of disseminating information,
because use of the internet alone would exclude many people from access
to information flows'.
This condition of a "digital divide" is illustrated well in Mathew Zook's
internet mapping projects. As his map of CONE and country code domains by
city shows, there is a vast concentration of domain names registered in
Europe, North America and the Asia Pacific. This data reinforces the claim
that advanced economies hold a geopolitical monopoly on informational flows,
and it follows that the intensity of networks will be greater in those cities
and regions with the highest concentration of domain names. Furthermore,
the socio-technical infrastructure in the form of services and so forth
that is necessary to support these informational nodes will also be greater
in those areas with higher concentrations of domain names.
According to statistics from the Ireland based web publishing and software
company NUA, there were approximately 580.78 million users connected to
the net in May 2002. Of this figure, 182.67 million and 167.86 million users
are located in North America and the Asia/Pacific respectively. In stark
contrast to this, Africa has 6.31 million users, and there are even less
in the Middle East, which has 5.12 million users. In percentage terms, Mathew
Zook's map of Internet Users Worldwide, which is based on NUA statistics,
registers less than 2 per cent of users in most African states, with the
exception of South Africa (4.9 - 13%), compared to over 35% connection rates
for populations in North America and Scandinavian countries. A recent report
published on NUA's site claims that in Africa there is 'roughly one internet
user for every 200 people, compared to a world average of one user for every
15 people, and a North American and European average of about one in every
2 people'. Interestingly (and not surprisingly), each connection in African
countries supports 3-5 users. Connections are confined to major cities,
with most capitals having more than one ISP. However, there are signs of
a recovery of sorts, with a 20 per cent increase in the number of dial-up
internet subscribers in the past year, according to this NUA report. This
shift can be accounted for by the rapid privatisation and deregulation of
state-owned telecommunications industries in many African countries over
the past year or so.
The relatively dismal connection rate for African states has prompted Castells
to make the pretty obvious point that 'Most of Africa is being left in a
technological apartheid…'. Such a condition has been compounded by economic
circumstances, with a steady decline in economic growth over the last decade
in Africa accompanied by substantial drops in the levels of Foreign Direct
Investment (FDI). As Ankie Hoogvelt notes, 'Africa's share of all FDI flows
to developing countries has dropped from 13 per cent in 1980 to less that
5 per cent in the late 1990s'. Referring to the crises in Asian "tiger"
economies in the late 90s, a recent report in the International Herald Tribune
noted that high levels of foreign investment flows are no a priori guarantee
to fast-tracking economic development: 'developing countries that allow
an inflow of foreign money into their financial markets are vulnerable to
disastrous, panicky withdrawals, especially if they have not developed sound
banking systems first'.
My point in detailing these vital statistics is not only to add some empirical
weight to my argument. I also want to signal that with this seeming change
to the telecommunications landscape in Africa, it is even more necessary
for major inroads to be made into the management and reform of IP rights
in African countries. As much as there might be a technological leap under
way in Africa, this is no guarantee that individuals and communities possess
the means to function within informational or knowledge economies in which
knowledge and ideas are 'embodied in products, processes and organisations',
which in turn 'fuel development'. Such a move requires a vast educational
infrastructure and cultural apparatuses and industries if information is
to be codified in symbolic forms as knowledge. It also requires investment
in 'sustaining the physical state of human capital (health expenditure)'.
Furthermore, such investment and infrastuctural needs has implications for
democracy formation, since the figure of the politically enabled citizen
presupposes an educated and healthy civilian; thus information flows depend
upon a civic infrastructure that includes schools, technical colleges, universities,
library resources, and so forth. One important precursor if not parallel
to such infrastructure consists of ensuring that indigenous cultural production
and biological knowledge is not alienated from local communities and individuals.
NGOs and IP and their relationship to the State
Whilst IP regimes can be understood as a form of abstraction that potentially
alienates production from labour, this is not necessarily a contradiction
in terms when IPRs are considered as a strategy to ensure a degree of economic
and political self-determination by indigenous peoples and those living
in developing or quasi-states. Intellectual property rights enable developing
states to place an economic value and regime of scarcity on their cultural
and biological resources. New ICTs are the mechanism for then distributing
this property and extracting financial remuneration from its use by those
participating in informational economies.
Furthermore, the codification of production as property reinforces the legal
authority of the state, since property cannot exist independently of state
recognition. That is, IPRs can assist in the development of the state apparatuses,
albeit ones that are circumscribed by economic interests, and reinstate
their authority to legislate progressive policy related to privacy rights
of their constituents. While IP in and of itself does not alleviate poverty
or misery, it does provide a crucial potential for leverage out of such
conditions, certainly more so than if IP is handed over to TNCs who have
a monopoly on ownership of both technology and product patents and copyright
of cultural production.
Of course there are numerous issues and problems associated with intellectual
property regimes as they currently figure. IP law reinforces what Castells
identifies as a key characteristic of the 'information age as a result of
its networking form of organization': namely, 'the growing individualization
of labor', and this functions to undermine collective bargaining or the
regulation of labour and wages by agreements between unions and the state.
Intellectual property regimes still attribute proprietary rights to an individual,
rather than a collective. In this regard, IP does not favour the social
form of production peculiar to many indigenous peoples and people in the
developing world, where production occurs through the form of the collective.
Further reform needs to occur to current intellectual property law that
legitimates ownership of knowledge that is not fixed in form, and enables
indigenous intellectual property to be protected in perpetuity. Herein lies
a challenge for NGOs at policy and legal levels.
Conclusion: whose democracy?
In conclusion, I would like to return to the title of my paper, 'whose democracy?'.
A couple of years ago when I first read Chantal Mouffe's The Democratic
Paradox, I questioned the extent to which her concept of agonistic or pluralist
democracy as a politics of legitimacy that enables 'the struggle between
adversaries' rather than antagonistic struggles between enemies was relevant
in any pragmatic sense within an informational age of network societies.
Certainly I thought Mouffe's identification of the antagonistic dimension
of "the political" as that which is underscored by the ineradicability of
violence, following the work of Schmitt and others, was insightful and timely
as rational consensus models gained even greater purchase as the only legitimate
models of democracy in town. But how, I wondered, was an agonistic politics
to be conditioned within the logic of informationalism?
The postnational ideological terrain of network societies has seen the apparatuses
of the state undergo deregulation and privatisation, or, in the case of
developing states, simply bypassed altogether. Mouffe's model of agonistic
democracy, which is predicated on traditional institutions of the state
as the place in which a democratic polity unfolds, seemed problematic and
decidedly modern in light of the reconfiguration of statehood at extraterritorial
and networked dimensions.
However, in light of my argument today on NGOs, the state, and intellectual
property regimes, I would suggest that it is precisely through pursuing
IP rights for indigenous peoples and civilian populations in quasi-states
that an agonistic politics might unfold. My reason for this is that IPRs
constitute a hegemonic field of articulation of "the political" in which
the identities of states, peoples, NGOs, corporations and supranational
entities are contested and reconstituted in ways that challenge a neoliberal
order as it currently stands (e.g. the imposition of structural adjustment
reforms on developing states by the IMF and World Bank as the condition
for financial aid). To avoid engaging with the problematic of IPRs is not
a political alternative.
The auxiliary task for NGOs is to ensure that the people they represent
are able to be situated as political actors within this networked terrain.
Such networks, as suggested by Florian Schneider, might be considered as
'packets in agony'. Political legitimacy, I would suggest, is conditioned
in the first instance by indigenous peoples obtaining economic sovereignty
which in turn positions them as political actors in as much informational
flows across scalar dimensions and the expansion of capital depends upon
engaging with what is otherwise a community of others excluded from informational
economies and network societies.
|